Search

Saturday, 10 February 2024

Labour's Industrial Strategy

John McTernan was unfortunate in his timing. His plea for Labour to drop the pretence that the green prosperity fund was anything other than an industrial strategy came only days before the long-heralded confirmation that the expected next government will not be spending £28 billion per year transitioning to a low-carbon future or anywhere near that figure. Lost in the debate over whether this latest u-turn shows Labour cleaving to the Tory agenda or simply incapable of sincerity is his use of a term suggesting a more dirigiste approach to the management of the economy than has been visible of late. As a confirmed Blairite, McTernan would no doubt insist that New Labour had an industrial strategy, but in substance this amounted to little more than acquiescence in the once-fashionable idea that letting the financial sector do as it pleased would ultimately benefit all. In fairness, that was a strategy with a long pedigree in British politics. The formal industrial strategy of the postwar years was, like the wider concept of planning, an atypical interlude in a history otherwise tending towards laissez faire.

The UK's fitful attempts to craft an industrial strategy between 1940 and 1980 reflected the nature of the economic model that developed over the much longer period between 1750 and 1890. The technological advances of the age, which every schoolkid learns to recite as a series of names (Arkwright, Bessemer, Stephenson etc), gave the UK a significant first-mover advantage as they did not spread sufficiently rapidly to allow other nations to quickly develop competitive domestic production. There were two consequences of this: the growth of export-oriented capital goods sectors in the UK (shipbuilding, railways etc) with the corollary of a firm commitment to free trade, and the defensive adoption of protectionist policies by many of those competitors in an effort to shield and develop domestic production (notably the USA). The common ground was a commitment to sound money - the gold standard - which in turn benefited the UK by making the City of London the central nexus of global trade and capital financing.

The extroverted nature of British industry led to sectors dominated by multiple, small-to-medium size manufacturers specialising in niche products and selling to a global market. In contrast, the protectionist policies of the UK's chief competitors encouraged vertical integration within captive domestic markets, the classic example being the development of Standard Oil in the US, a company that spanned extraction, refining, distribution and retail (a model that remains central to the oil business today). The institutional effect of this was the emergence of the large-scale corporation and a tendency towards merger as a means of achieving growth, particularly notable in Germany around steel production, which was only occasionally restrained by anti-trust laws (e.g. the break-up of Standard Oil). After World War II proved the inefficiency of further expansion through territorial aggression, this birthed the modern multinational. 


While all this was going on, the UK found itself pulled between competing interests. The established capital goods and manufacturing sectors lobbied government to preserve their export markets, which gave rise to the conflict between free trade and imperial preference (the latter being an attempt to stunt the growth of capital production and manufacturing in the colonies, which inevitably failed because no one seemed to appreciate that this wasn't what the dominions themselves wanted). Meanwhile, there was a conscious effort to consolidate the fragmented primary goods and manufacturing sectors during the twentieth century, notably coal, steel and automobile production. Typically, this was done by a combination of nationalisation, the encouragement of private sector mergers, and various schemes in between where the state would act as a sleeping partner underwriting private capital with public money. 

What remained a constant was the interests of high finance and the influence it exerted on the UK state - what Giovanni Arrighi, in The Long Twentieth Century, refered to as its "pecuniary rationality". Despite the retreat from the gold standard and the emergence of capital markets in New York and Tokyo, the City of London continued to exert sway over the state's fiscal policy and industrial strategy, constraining the former (the "Treasury view") and showing little enthusiasm for the latter. Indeed, if nationalisation in the UK was characterised by a willingness to preserve the existing management culture and resist workers' control, it was also marked by a desire to side-step the City's lack of interest in domestic opportunities and to short-cut the process of private sector consolidation. The problem was that the fiscal constraints inevitably led to under-investment in those nationalised industries by the state: neither brave enough to defy the money markets nor brave enough to reform British management.

The technological first-mover advantage that the UK benefited from in the late-eighteenth and early-nineteenth centuries (roughly 1760-1840) now looks like a historical one-off, both in terms of the transformative effects it had on society (e.g. urbanisation) and in its duration, though you could make an argument for China's economic catch-up since 1978 being an echo of it, albeit through the absorption of common technologies into an untapped domestic market and then through labour cost arbitrage with the West. Subsequent cycles of advance, notably the second industrial revolution (1870-1914) and more recently the digital revolution (1970-1990), saw new technologies dispersed globally in ever more rapid bursts. This in turn means that the boost to GDP growth arising from new technologies tends to be weaker and much shorter. While tech-boosterism is still a thing among politicians and pundits, the likes of Tony Blair look increasingly naive in their fetishistic belief that the embrace of technology alone can transform a nation's fortunes. 


Today, growth above the historic mean, or even above the level of national comparators, can only arise in two ways. One is a historic conjuncture in which secular trends and contingent opportunities coincide to produce a benign environment. For example, a demographic bulge that rapidly adds youth to the working population or the demands of reconstruction after a period of major destruction. The second is a major change in the composition of the economy that provides a higher-level comparative advantage. For example, the discovery of oil, or other valuable resources, within a territory or the rapid expansion of an export-oriented industry that cannot be quickly replicated by competitors (such as semiconductor fabrication). Of course, these developments themselves entail risks, notably the resource curse in the first instance and exposure to fluctuating foreign demand and currency speculation in the second. A safer approach may be a state-led change in the compostion of the economy but for a developed nation with already mature technology like the UK such a change is more difficult to achieve: you can't just take it off the shelf as the Chinese did.

Outside these exceptional circumstances, the ambition for most states will be growth close to the international average. For developed economies, that's been around 2% per annum over the last twenty years. The UK is currently at about 0.5%, so there's certainly headroom, but getting closer to 2% won't generate the sort of tax incomes, ceteris paribus, required to fund much long-term investment, particularly given the demands to boost day-to-day spending on the NHS, social care and crumbling local goverment services. The green prosperity fund - or green new deal if you prefer, emphasising the pro-labour and pro-social aspects - offered a potential way out of this bind: a major retooling that would boost growth in the short-term and make the economy more competitive in the longer-term so sustaining that growth (or at least enabling the UK to keep up with its peer group). In rejecting the idea of using the green transition to boost growth, Labour are not simply allowing the Tories to set the agenda, or giving up on the climate crisis, they are confirming that the stranglehold of the City, last seen during the Truss debacle, remains very much in place. 

Labour hasn't been the party of the workers since the 1970s, and even then workerism was only one of a number of competing ideological strands, but it did retain a credible claim to be the party of growth long past that point and as recently as 2019. With this announcement, Starmer and Reeves have confirmed that it has given up that claim and is now simply the party of sound money: the "fiscal rules" have become a fetishistic end in themselves rather than the means to a particular fiscal end (higher spending, lower taxes etc). The move to the right on policy (i.e. all those promises reneged), like the authoritarianism and managerial brutality, are not simply the instinctive behaviours of the right wing of the party. They are an expression of an overarching commitment to sound money that inevitably produces a conservative, pessimistic mindset and a preference for austerity: the constraint of the growth they claim to be in favour of. Labour has no industrial strategy because it has no growth strategy beyond a pious hope.

11 comments:

  1. Interesting high quality piece as usual. There is no mention of defence ( or war ) in the analysis. I wonder if you have looked at David Edgerton's Warfare State: Britain, 1920–1970. If you have would be interested in your thoughts and on Edgerton's anti declinist arguments more generally.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. War is there in "the demands of reconstruction after a period of major destruction". I've read Edgerton's The Rise and Fall of the British Nation, which I believe recapitulates the main arguments of his earlier book. I broadly agree with his anti-declinist stance, but it's worth emphasising that his point is not that decline didn't happen but that the efforts to arrest & reverse it came to naught due to the power of finance over government.

      Delete
    2. I think Edgerton's point (like Jim Tomlinson, who is also worth reading) is very much that decline didn't happen other than in the sense that as the first industrial power the UK was bound to see its position weaken vis-a-vis other nations. It was the same for the US as its relative economic position shifted after WW2. Edgerton even goes as far as to suggest that the Thatcher governments intervened quite intensively in the 1980s in soon-to-be privatised utilities.

      In one sense McTernan was definitely right, that the 'Green New Deal' is an industrial strategy by another name. In effect, it's a cover for a massive Keynesian deficit finance strategy, and as such could never be 'Green'. Completely re-equipping industry and rolling out electronic cars for everyone in the short-term would be utterly destructive of the environment, even if it was plausible. It would use levels of energy that could not be completely provided by renewable sources, would require vast amounts of open-cast mining of resources such as lithium, and would produce huge quantities of waste.

      The only practical strategy from an environmental point of view is to promote reuse and repair of existing items, coupled with the gradual production of new items that last for decades. This, however, will be rejected as politically impossible. As such, there is no solution that does not involve restraint and moderation and that would not involve the winding-down of capitalism and modern cosumerism.

      Delete
    3. There's obviously a contradiction, or at least a tension, between major investment to move to low-carbon energy and the sort of de-growth necessary to avoid simply shifting environmental despoliation from fossil fuels to other natural resources. Unfortunately, it doesn't look like we're going to get anywhere near to a substantive debate on the issue, another example of how "pecuniary rationality" crowds out policy.

      Delete
    4. I certainly agree on that point.

      Delete
    5. Indeed. The amount of copper required for the energy transition is vast. This can only come from large-scale, low-grade deposits in countries like Chile, Bolivia, Peru and Mexico. The grade of these deposits is about 3% in the upper parts of the deposit but less than 1% in the lower parts. Removing most of the waste material occurs on-site through various processes that use considerable amounts of water (in quite arid areas). The large amounts of waste material are left behind as tailings in tailings dams, which are high-risk structures (as shown by two disasters in Brazil in the last 10 years). Mining companies are working on other technologies to process ore but these are unlikely to be available at-scale in the next 10 years.

      The Green New Deal put the energy transition on the political map in a very fuzzy way but even that, it is claimed, frightens voters. We are nowhere near having a debate based on the fact that countries with copper mines may not accept the risks of large tailings dams or the use of their water for mineral processing.

      Delete


  2. drop the pretence that the green prosperity fund was anything other than an industrial strategy [...] McTernan would no doubt insist that New Labour had an industrial strategy»

    The biggest pretence is that there has been no "industrial strategy" when instead there has been one, to subsidise heavily the real estate and finance sectors, with enormous amounts of public money.

    This has been done by a tight fiscal policy to force interest rates lower, and outright handing out of hundreds of billions of welfare in 2008 and subsequent years. The goal was to keep weakening productive industries because infected or infectable by trade unionism, and keep rewarding the "sponsors" of the political class.

    «but in substance this amounted to little more than acquiescence in the once-fashionable idea that letting the financial sector do as it pleased»

    If this "laissez-faire" has been the policy then interest rates would not have been pushed down so hard and in 2008 most of the City would have gone bankrupt and also the property sector. This is how the arch-neoliberal "laissez faire" people at "The Economist" argued at the time:

    http://www.economist.com/node/21542417/
    Britain will one day wake up to discover that it has lost one of the world's most successful business clusters, and the best hope the next generation has of earning a decent living.

    That's an impassioned argument for handing out hundred of billions of welfare to the City to subsidise the plum jobs of the next generation of the southern upper-middle class.

    ReplyDelete
  3. «the economic model that developed over the much longer period between 1750 and 1890. The technological advances of the age, which every schoolkid learns to recite as a series of names (Arkwright, Bessemer, Stephenson etc), gave the UK a significant first-mover advantage as they did not spread sufficiently rapidly to allow other nations to quickly develop competitive domestic production.»

    Indeed, from from E. Wrigley, "Energy and the english industrial revolution" (2010):
    “Approximately two-thirds of the European production of cotton textiles took place in the UK. The comparable percentages for iron production and coal production were 64 and 76 per cent. [...] The total of installed steam engine horsepower was far larger than on the continent. In 1840, 75 per cent of the combined total capacity of stationary steam engines inare in exclusive and unilateral Britain, France, Prussia and Belgium was in Britain alone (the other three countries accounted for the great bulk of installed capacity on the continent.”

    ReplyDelete
  4. «the interests of high finance and the influence it exerted on the UK state - what Giovanni Arrighi, in The Long Twentieth Century, refered to as its "pecuniary rationality".»

    That was also commented upon by JM Keynes much earlier:

    https://jmaynardkeynes.ucc.ie/national-self-sufficiency.html
    John Maynard Keynes "National Self-Sufficiency" The Yale Review (1933-06)
    «The nineteenth century carried to extravagant lengths the criterion of what one can call for short "the financial results," as a test of the advisability of any course of action sponsored by private or by collective action. The whole conduct of life was made into a sort of parody of an accountant's night-mare. Instead of using their vastly increased material and technical resources to build a wonder city, the men of the nineteenth century built slums; and they thought it right and advisable to build slums because slums, on the test of private enterprise, “paid”, whereas the wonder city would, they thought, have been an act of foolish extravagance, which would, in the imbecile idiom of the financial fashion, have “mortgaged the future” – though how the construction to-day of great and glorious works can impoverish the future, no man can see until his mind is beset by false analogies from an irrelevant accountancy.»

    The difficulty that JM disregarded so easily is that the benefit of a "wonder city" would have gone to different people from those who would have financed it.

    ReplyDelete
  5. «Completely re-equipping industry and rolling out electronic cars for everyone in the short-term would be utterly destructive of the environment»

    This point was made made in detail here:

    https://www.coppolacomment.com/2021/03/from-carbon-to-metals-renewable-energy.html
    “Low-carbon technologies are considerably more metal-intensive than fossil fuel-based technologies. [...] Rising demand for metals due to the adoption of low-carbon technologies could perversely increase emissions and worsen environmental damage."

    There is always the possibility that "carbon footprint" was actually means to achieve "consume less oil" for economic reasons rather than "less impact on the climate".

    ReplyDelete
  6. «Starmer and Reeves have confirmed that it has given up that claim and is now simply the party of sound money: the "fiscal rules" have become a fetishistic end in themselves rather than the means to a particular fiscal end (higher spending, lower taxes etc).»

    That is called in the old jargon "the Treasury View" but it is not fetishism, because "sound money has two important actual purposes:

    * To keep the real economy moderated so as to reduce the negotiating power of workers (so that it takes 6 month to find a job rather than 6 months to fill a vacancy).

    * To keep the credit economy un-moderated so as to have booming asset prices, in particular residential property, because that is what drives voting for thatcherism.

    http://www.theguardian.com/business/2011/sep/23/stock-market-rout-eurozone-crisis
    «Osborne admitted that the darkening international economic outlook would have repercussions for the UK but insisted that he had no intention of amending his tough deficit reduction plans. It was up to the Bank of England, he added, to support demand over the coming months. "A credible fiscal plan allows you to have a looser monetary policy than would otherwise be the case. My approach is to be fiscally conservative but monetarily active."»

    That is given a fixed inflation target a tight fiscal policy "forces" the BoE to have a loose credit policy, for the benefit of incumbent asset owners.

    Thanks to "sound money" real wages since 2008 have fallen on average by 8% and real southern property prices have boomed by 60-80%. Imagine an average worker on 25k a year in 2008 buying a 150k property: they have lost around 16k in real wages since 2008 but gained 120k in property profit, and guess what matters more to them and which way they are going to vote. Rah! Rah!

    ReplyDelete