Search

Friday 5 May 2023

The Capability of the State

The coronation has inevitably led to many state-of-the-nation essays and none has captured the essentially sombre and fearful mood more than Ian MacIlhagga's claim, in the relatively obscure US magazine Palladium, that "Britain is dead". This comes from a technocratic and centrist political space concerned with effective governance (the non-profit American Governance Foundation), so it is impeccably liberal in its reasoning, but being a foreign perspective means it avoids the usual self-congratulation and personalism that mars domestic liberal analyses. Boris Johnson is mentioned only in passing while Dominic Cummings is cited as an ultimately defeated reformer of the Civil Service whose intentions were laudable. In a useful corrective to the dominance of the popular narrative by historically and sociologically illiterate controversialists like Matthew Goodwin, the author is under no illusions about who composes the governing elite, even if his routine declinism is questionable.

MacIlhagga's charge is essentially a rehash of Martin Wiener's thesis, in the 1981 book English Culture and the Decline of the Industrial Spirit, 1850-1980, that the UK's steady fall from economic and geopolitical dominance can be traced to the continued social pre-eminence of aristocratic values (anti-industrial and anti-mercantile), which first seduced the industrial bourgeosie in the nineteenth century, persuading them to buy landed estates and chase honours, and then infected the emerging middle class in the twentieth, as seen in the persistence of private schooling and a general flippancy towards governance ("a culture of amateurism"). Despite this liberal lineage, there are also odd bits of the Anderson-Nairn thesis in the essay - the "premature death" of the "modernizing class" after the Glorious Revolution - though the paradox of an anti-industrial aristocracy that embraced capitalism isn't really addressed, suggesting MacIlhagga's reading didn't extend to Ellen Meiksens Wood.

But while there is little novelty in this thumbnail history, what is of the moment is the focus on the state's capability, which McIlhagga defines negatively as "the British elite’s profound inability to prevent national decline". In a litany of failed reform, that amusingly links Cecil Rhodes to Cummings, MacIlhagga acknowledges that this wasn't a tale of steady and comprehensive decline - "The pressures of the following two world wars forced the British state to retain a high level of capacity and an ability to mobilize effectively" - but he insists that the established habits led to an under-performing economy and poor scientific productivity from the late-1940s onwards. Again, he appears not to have read the scholarship on the subject, notably David Edgerton's The Rise and Fall of the British Nation. The result is an inescapable pessimism: "In the end, every technocratic policy fix has been recuperated into managed decline. Buoyed up by soft power and high-paying financial services, even the UK’s would-be reformers drastically underestimate the human capital problem that affects every layer of society".


Where MacIlhagga most obviously shows the influence of Wiener is in his belief that the British malaise is essentially cultural, and by that he means the culture of the elite: "After a multi-generational failure by the British state to assess its hard constraints and build up a materially productive social order, its elites appear to have fundamentally lost interest in governance". This is supported by predictable criticisms of the utility of elite education, notably the Oxford PPE course, and the generalist bent of the upper reaches of the Civil Service. What it fails to do is acknowledge that there are plenty of people in the UK who have not lost interest in governance but that they are effectively denied access to power by a politico-media establishment in which the purpose of elite education is to preserve that elite, not to equip recruits with appropriate technocratic skills (James Schneider is the one interviewee to correctly note that education is a red herring). This leads MacIlhagga to frame "an absolute decline in state capacity" and "a breakdown among colleagues of the basic trust in each other to get things done" as essentially a HR problem.

The dominant motif in British politics is the idea that there are major areas of public policy that the state cannot effect. This is not simply the neoliberal idea that the provision of the means of social reproduction, such as health and housing, should be left to the market, but a more profound belief in the incapability of the UK state in the context of historic decline. In other words, declinism is a interpretative choice that excuses inaction. The idea that areas of national life, from the monarchy to "rural England", should be preserved - that we shouldn't risk change and should "prefer the tried to the untried", as Michael Oakeshott put it - is obviously central to conservative thinking, but this has to be allied with the progressive impetus of modernity - the ceaseless appetite for novelty, the relentless exploitation of resources etc. In Britain this has produced a schizophrenic political culture in which the rhetoric of modernisation and growth coexists with a profound aversion to meaningful change.

An outside observer might wonder at the tactical nous of the Tories banging on about the "small boats" of asylum-seekers in the Channel, given that this is an intractable problem for which the only outcomes are relative degrees of failure in the eyes of the rightwing press. But this would be to misunderstand the spectacle. The outsourcing of asylum processing to Rwanda isn't simply an "out of sight, out of mind" manoeuvre. It serves to highlight the limited capability of the UK state, which is the governance analog of the claim that "We're full up" and that public services lack the capacity to accommodate immigration. Likewise, the same observer might be nonplussed by the lack of ambition on display from the Labour Party when there are so many obvious areas for improvement. While Starmer and his front bench have emphasised reform, this is very much in the sense of a continuation of the work of the New Labour years. There will be no nationalisation of the water companies, private providers will be further entrenched in the NHS and the state will limit itself to producing targets and metrics.


This cross-party consensus on the limited role of government is perhaps most obvious in housing. The state's role in the provision of accommodation was the emblematic social policy of the twentieth century, from the "Homes fit for heroes" demand after World War One to the priority of housing starts in the Labour and Conservative parties' electoral offers after World War Two. The roots of the current "crisis" go back beyond the Thatcher government's introduction of Right-to-Buy to a cross-party consensus on the need to reduce the state's role in housebuilding that began to emerge in the mid-1970s as part of the neoliberal shift. It was the Callaghan government that first considered a national policy of allowing tenants to purchase their council homes but shelved it due to concerns over its "indiscriminate" nature, the management of which would have required significant state intervention. Thatcher cut the Gordian Knot by the simple expedient of adopting a free-for-all policy that privileged occupiers and forcibly removing local government from supply.

The problem today is not that we haven't built enough homes but that property is unequally distributed, both in the sense of who owns or occupies what and in the sense that too much capital is tied up in it and thus unavailable for more productive investment. The long inflation in house prices cannot be divorced from the accelerated decline of British industry in the early-80s any more than deregulation of mortgage financing in that decade. It was the combination that diverted (initially domestic) capital and savings into property. The demand for a more holistic view of housing than simply how to get more first-time buyers onto the ladder is correct, but it doesn't go far enough if you don't perceive the housing problem to be one of the allocation of real economic resources, and that in turn raises questions about the role of the state in economic management. The narrative of relative decline ignores the absolute progress of society: despite the inadequate housing conditions of the poor, we have fewer slums today, fewer people sharing beds or bedrooms, and tenants have far more rights than they did a century ago. 

As David Edgerton noted more broadly, "declinism took to explaining what never happened with explanations that didn't work." The retreat of the state in the 1970s was not the product of either intrinsic weaknesses in British elite culture or of structural forces such as imperialism's neglect of domestic industry (the left critique) or the democratic indulgence of the welfare state (the right critique). Rather it came about because of a conscious decision to limit the agency of the state, a decision that had its roots in the liberal struggles over the expansion of the state in the first quarter of the twentieth century. Samuel MacIlhagga is right to trace the paralysis of the British elite back to the little-known Coefficients dining club formed by Sidney and Beatrice Webb in 1902, but he misses the point that the attempt to unite the "progressive" Webbs with liberal and conservative politicians such as Richard Haldane and Alfred Milner highlighted the exclusive nature of the British political elite: the club. It is this exclusivity that remains the fundamental problem in British governance and everything that has occurred in politics since 2015 suggests its defence remains paramount.

10 comments:

  1. Perhaps I'm misunderstanding, but British investing doesn't need to be made more appealing to attract capital away from housing. Low cost global trackers already serve that purpose. If Brits were better educated they'd realise trackers + renting is better than dumping money in illiquid, decaying property.

    Or perhaps you mean the government should offer tax advantaged UK investment opportunities? Like NS&I? In which case, ok.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. «but British investing doesn't need to be made more appealing to attract capital away from housing. Low cost global trackers already serve that purpose.»

      Global trackers invest globally, they don't invest in UK productive activities and UK capital development.

      «If Brits were better educated they'd realise trackers + renting is better than dumping money in illiquid, decaying property.»

      Two examples:

      Commenter on "theguardian.com", 2018: «I inherited two properties in 1995 [ ... ] and the value has gone from £95,000 to £1,100,000»
      A 79-year-old retired carpenter in Cornwall: «who bought his council house in Devon in the early 80s for £17,000. When it was valued at £80,000 in 1989, he sold up and used the equity to put towards a £135,000 fisherman’s cottage in St Mawes. Now it’s valued at £1.1m. “I was very grateful to Margaret Thatcher,” he said.»

      Southern english property can be be bought on 20 times leverage (e.g. "Help to Buy", even if the average has been 10 times leverage, and in some periods with no deposit at all), doubles in prices every 7-10 years, capital gains and imputed rent on the main property are tax-free, it is often easy to cheat tax on BTL rents paid in cash.

      The result is that property speculators who bought 20-30 years ago have enjoyed safe, long term net APRs of 50-70%, compound. Any dips have been fixed by the government, money-no-object. The whole property and finance sectors are the target of massive state intervention to keep them booming, not just because of the "plunge protection teams" at the treasury and central bank.

      https://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/enterprise/11929491/Lord-Sugar-tells-his-Apprentice-to-invest-in-property-if-he-wants-to-be-wealthy-in-business.html
      «Speaking about his first year in business with Lord Sugar, Mark Wright, the winner of last year’s Apprentice, said the Amstrad founder had given him tips on creating long-term wealth. “Lord Sugar said you make money from property and do business for fun. Many of our customers make money from property and I’d love to go into property development one day,” said Mr Wright.»

      Only a complete imbecile would waste their money by throwing it at productive businesses in the UK given that: businesses take time to manage, are taxed, are not government guaranteed, cannot be funded on 20 times leverage, you can't live in them either, and usually fail.

      Delete
    2. From The Return on Everything (NBER, 2015), table 7, real average return % p/y on:

      UK housing post 1950: 6.57
      Global weighted equity post 1950: 8.19

      UK housing post 1980: 6.81
      Global weighted equity post 1980: 9.08

      This is largely driven by the inflating valuation (yet feeble productivity) of big tech, the global driver of which SE property inflation is spillover.

      Delete
    3. N.B. The housing return is total; price appreciation plus rental income (actual or imputed).

      Delete
  2. I am sorry to say that I think the arguments in this post are based on what it seems to me a huge "misunderstanding", of american origin, that the size and capability of the state is the central topic of right-wing politics, because:

    * It is part of the notion that politics is about ideas and principles rather than material interests, as if the right-wingers thought "whether it benefits our interests or not, a smaller state is regardless what we want".

    * It is factually obviously wrong: there has been a gigantic amount of state intervention in the economy in the past 40 years of thatcherism, but nearly always in favour of finance and property, and via credit/monetary policy. As reflected in the stupendous sums handed out to failed finance and property speculators in past and in the recent past.

    Two classic quotes:

    «Osborne admitted that the darkening international economic outlook would have repercussions for the UK but insisted that he had no intention of amending his tough deficit reduction plans. It was up to the Bank of England, he added, to support demand over the coming months. “A credible fiscal plan allows you to have a looser monetary policy than would otherwise be the case. My approach is to be fiscally conservative but monetarily active.”»

    «It is hard to overstate the fundamental importance of low interest rates for an economy as indebted as ours… …and the unthinkable damage that a sharp rise in interest rates would do.
    When you’ve got a mountain of private sector debt, built up during the boom… …low interest rates mean indebted businesses and families don’t have to spend every spare pound just paying their interest bills. In this way, low interest rates mean more money to spare to invest for the future. A sharp rise in interest rates – as has happened in other countries which lost the world’s confidence – would put all this at risk… …with more businesses going bust and more families losing their homes.»

    I reckon that the framing of the politics debate on the size and capability of the state has been designed to mislead both as to the colossal sums handed out to property and finance interests, and that there has been a huge switch from fiscal to credit/monetary policy, with the BoE balance sheet exploding to support massive state intervention in the markets.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. The post isn't about the size of the state, or about the extent of its intervention in the economy, but about the cross-party consensus on what it is appropriate for the state to do (e.g. prop up asset prices but not housebuilding), which it traces to the exclusivity of the establishment (the actual elite).

      Delete
    2. «The post isn't about the size of the state, or about the extent of its intervention in the economy»

      I guess that it could be read with some effort this way, but then I must have misunderstood the meaning of parts like “The dominant motif in British politics is the idea that there are major areas of public policy that the state cannot effect”, “This cross-party consensus on the limited role of government is perhaps most obvious in housing”, “it came about because of a conscious decision to limit the agency of the state, a decision that had its roots in the liberal struggles over the expansion of the state in the first quarter of the twentieth century” which gave me the impression that the main argument was the expansion or contraction of the state.

      «the cross-party consensus on what it is appropriate for the state to do (e.g. prop up asset prices but not housebuilding)»

      Indeed, a consensus which is usually called "thatcherism".

      Delete
  3. «In Britain this has produced a schizophrenic political culture in which the rhetoric of modernisation and growth coexists with a profound aversion to meaningful change.»

    I think that is because that “political culture” in the UK means largely “thatcherism” and that is like the Conservative and [Liberal] Unionist Party itself a mix of both "whig" and "tory" politics, where for example the Conservative base are mostly (nationalist) "tory" but a plurality and perhaps a majority of the Conservative elite are (globalist) "whig". My understanding of "neoliberalism" is that it is "neo" in that while being mostly Victorian Liberal whiggism, it also has strong elements of torysm, where the protection of (some) vested interests is more important than "laissez fair" (as the BoE balance sheet explosion demonstrates).

    Thatcher herself seems to me to have had both politics, perhaps broadly "whig" on economic matters and "tory" on social values.

    “Peregrine Worsthorne [Telegraph journalist] once said that, ‘Margaret Thatcher came into Downing Street determined to recreate the world of her father and ended up creating the world of her son.’ It’s a pretty damning assessment but it’s actually quite true.”»

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. «it is "neo" in that while being mostly Victorian Liberal whiggism, it also has strong elements of torysm, where the protection of (some) vested interests is more important than "laissez fair" (as the BoE balance sheet explosion demonstrates).»
      the cross-party consensus on what it is appropriate for the state to do (e.g. prop up asset prices but not housebuilding)

      To illustrate one of my most cherished quotes, where the mask is dropped completely, from the ultra-neroliberal "The Economist", when advocating unlimited state intervention to subsidize the finance and property sectors by handing them out hundreds of billions of free-at-the-point-of-use capital:

      http://www.economist.com/node/21542417
      «Britain will one day wake up to discover that it has lost one of the world's most successful business clusters, and the best hope the next generation has of earning a decent living»

      Between the Treasury and the Bank Of England nearly a trillion pounds has ben handed out generously to “one of the world's most successful [at scrounging from the state] business clusters”, a big-state intervention in the markets to ensure that a few dozen thousands from the next generation of independent school and Oxbridge educated elites have a “decent living”, and too bad for the rest. A lot more state money has been used in a few years to subsidize the “decent living” of those elites than over decades in the past to support the jobs of steel, car, etc. workers.

      Delete
  4. «predictable criticisms of the utility of elite education, notably the Oxford PPE course, and the generalist bent of the upper reaches of the Civil Service.»

    I remember this book mentioning that already: T. Balogh "The apotheosis of the dilettante" (1959).

    ReplyDelete