The popular discussion of economics divides into macro and micro, with those familiar with the former tending to adopt a slightly patronising attitude towards the latter (the legacy of Keynes' de haut en bas style), which in turn sees them map onto a left-right spectrum. This is misleading, not only because macroeconomics has historically been an attempt to reconcile classical liberalism with the reality of the state as an economic actor, thereby excluding the need for a socialist or Marxist analysis, but because it tends to omit large swathes of the real economy. A famous example was the lack of attention paid to finance and banking as a systemic vulnerability prior to 2008. But an even more prevalent omission in the popular macroeconomic discourse, which was once central to economics in the days of Adam Smith and David Ricardo, is the role of rent.
Smith laid out the basic proposition: "The rent of land, therefore, considered as the price paid for the use of the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned to what the landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land, or to what he can afford to take; but to what the farmer can afford to give." Ricardo formulated this as a general law, to wit that the rent of a piece of land will equal the additional monetary gain of its productive use relative to the production of a rent-free piece of land. In other words, tenant farmers will desert high-rent land if the rent exceeds the marginal loss they would incur by farming a rent-free piece of land.
This theory was useful in an era when many people were tenant farmers and when colonialism was bringing marginal (i.e. rent-free) land into production, so the idea of farmers upping sticks to find a more economically advantageous plot wasn't as unrealistic as it seems to us today. Obviously the externalities of colonialism were ignored while rent was seen as a product of natural endowment - the gift of heaven - and the industry of white colonisers (cf Locke). Subsequent attempts, e.g. by Marx, were made to focus on the capital investment of land, its improvement in Smith's terms, and how natural endowment in reality gives rise to rentierism, i.e. monopoly exploitation, notably in the area of patents and technical innovation (as theorised by Joseph Schumpeter).
The one area of rent that has tended to receive far less attention from economists, in terms of explaining what determines its price, is the rent of property, and specifically houses and flats. This might seem odd given how large rent looms in our lives. Even if you have bought a property or are currently paying a mortgage to do so, you are subject to rent insofar as house prices will always reflect the equivalent contract rent - i.e. what you could get if you let it over the same period as a typical mortgage (hence buy-to-let). Many people assume that the dynamic of this relationship works in the opposite direction: high house prices lead to high rents, and that rising house prices are simply the consequence of demand outstripping supply, hence the arguments that we should ease planning restrictions or curtail immigration, but this ignores that there is no shortage of empty or under-occupied houses and flats across the country. So what determines rent?
The law of supply says that more goods will be produced at higher prices. In other words, if demand for a commodity grows, thereby pushing up the price, producers will increase output to take advantage of the larger demand and thus fatter profit margins. The law of demand says that at higher prices demand falls. So once supply of that commodity exceeds demand, following that increase in output, prices will fall back to their notional equilibrium level. This simplistic model obviously ignores a lot of real world frictions and contraints. For example, not all commodities can be rapidly produced at a higher rate, e.g. by adding shifts or converting existing production lines. Likewise, if the market is cartelised there may be a reluctance among producers to increase output excessively. OPEC is the obvious example here.
In the case of housing, there are real constraints such as restrictive planning regulations and limited real resources (builders and building materials), but the biggest determinant is the reluctance of volume builders to over-supply the market and so depress prices. In this context, the state is a volume builder that has taken a self-denying ordinance to maintain house prices, both for owner-occupiers and landlords, which is why the UK government is so reluctant to build council houses despite the pressing need, and why US liberals like Ezra Klein and Derek Thompson argue that "abundance" can be achieved by simply rolling back regulations and striking out building codes, which provides an easy excuse to ignore capitalist realities in favour of a technocratic can-doism.
The "law" of demand is also undermined by necessity. In other words, there are certain things we have to buy, at least at a minimal level, such as shelter, food and clothing, lest we risk injury or death (self-sufficiency is not a practical strategy for most people and a return to a subsistence economy would result in mass starvation). We cannot realistically choose not to buy shelter, preferring to spend our money on first editions or champagne, so demand cannot fall to such low levels that prices must drop. Equally, we cannot easily cut back on the amount we spend on shelter, unlike certain other necessities such as food or clothes. We can skip meals or wear socks with holes in them, but we can't decide to move to a cheaper flat for a month and then back again to ease our cashflow.
When we talk of "the housing market" (singular) we are dealing in a fantasy. In reality, there are hundreds, if not thousands, of geographically limited housing markets, which estate and letting agents understand only too well. Goods (i.e. houses and flats) cannot be moved from one market to another, so prices must always reflect local circumstances. We also cannot easily choose to buy from alternative suppliers in cheaper markets. If I work in London but can't afford the rent, there's no point renting a flat in Sunderland. And if I got an equivalent job in Sunderland, it might not pay well enough to allow me to rent there either.
When house prices or rents do fall, that is typically because of a relative over-supply in a limited geographical market. But when this happens it is rarely because the quantum of supply rapidly increases. Instead it is because the quantum of demand rapidly falls. The obvious examples are all around us: areas that saw deindustrialisation in the 1980s with the result that the population shrank. But the fall in house prices and rents in those areas also reflects the lower average income of the remaining population: deindustrialisation typically took away above-average wage jobs, and they were above-average in most cases due to the strength of trade unions in heavy industries like coal, steel and shipbuilding. Outside these geographic exceptions, house prices and rents rarely if ever fall, something that cannot be explained away as price "stickiness" or the lower bound of a zero return on capital.
Rents then will always reflect "what the market can bear", which is a polite way of saying that landlords will push prices up to their maximum: the point where tenants can just about afford them, assuming they're willing to limit expenditure on other goods, which may be discretionary, such as entertainment, but may also be necessities, such as food and clothing. The "cost of living crisis" due to the recent spike in food and energy costs shouldn't distract from the fact that the prices of these other necessities are, in real terms, a fraction of what they were 50 years ago. That rents have grown over this period is not because people have felt that housing was a better choice for their discretionary expenditure, despite the relentless media propaganda, but because landlords have, in Smith's words, constantly recalibrated what the tenant can afford to give.
Owner-occupier incumbents restricting new market entrants constitute a cartel — one that can be busted across most of the US by removing their ability to block density via zoning. This makes the technocratic approach you denigrate as "ignoring capitalist realities" into one of the more potent tools against precisely the owners of capital assets causing the problem.
ReplyDeleteThe capitalist reality is that at the same time as we're seeing capital's share of GDP grow relative to wages we are also seeing an ever-increasing share of those wages being recycled into capital rather than consumption. Klein and Thompson are suggesting that what ails society is an unwillingness to allow capital even more freedom that it has at present.
Delete"Building dense housing" is the capital freedom you want to restrict? What about the freedom of rich incumbent owner-occupiers to capture regulatory power in order to keep other, less wealthy people from moving into dense housing near them — any problem with that?
DeleteIf I have understood correctly, FATE has answered your point more generically. In the states it sounds like capital uses existing regulatory structures to inhibit dense residential building construction. Your proposal would be to remove the restriction- this being a technocratic solution to a specific problem of zoning and that might work for a while to be fair (I don’t know). The point though is that unless and until a non-profit maximising entity starts mass building (ie the state) the problem won’t be solved, so in your case what capital could do and has done is build those residences and leave them half empty. Or buy the land and leave it undeveloped (if challenged such a developer could blame some kind of regulation etc and the game continues).
DeleteThere is also in this the role of the finance industry in this, as a land purchase and higher values allow them to leverage more money to gamble with.
That last paragraph should read as follows:
DeleteThere is also in this the role of the finance industry, as their land purchases together with increases in prices allow them to leverage more money to gamble with.
Changing zoning and density rules hardly constitutes a 'technocratic' approach, they exist deliberately to perpetuate the existing system of property and power relationships, and to scrap or radically alter them would require determined political action against the very people who make financial decisions relating to capital spending. The idea that wealthy property-owners and finance capitalists are chomping at the bit waiting to build 20-storey tower blocks in the gardens of million-pound-plus houses seems somewhat naive.
DeleteThis is a post that I mostly agree with and will provide later a number of quotes and references to support many of the statements in it, but this is just about mechanics of how rent is determined, the "what" as in the title:
ReplyDelete«the biggest determinant is the reluctance of volume builders to over-supply the market and so depress prices. In this context, the state is a volume builder that has taken a self-denying ordinance to maintain house prices, both for owner-occupiers and landlords»
The "why" is far more important in our current circumstances and that is the ruthless political will to buy the support and votes of the middle-class for thatcherism/reaganism by gifting them massive redistribution from the lower classes via property profits:
* The fundamental goal of thatcherism is to lower wages, pensions, social insurance to redistribute from the lower classes to the upper class and the main problem with that is most people earn wages, rely on pensions and often need social insurance, so they would not vote for that...
* ...Unless a large minority were more than compensated for falling wages, smaller pensions, meaner social insurance with massive property profits via higher housing costs redistributed from the lower classes. Such redistributed profits usually amount to a near doubling of the after-tax income of property owners in those areas, so they are a compelling factor.
* So the policy of all governments in the USA, UK, Eire, etc. has been to ensure booming property rents and prices in large enough areas to create a big enough block of rentiers from those areas so that a solid plurality of voters support thatcherite parties (Conservatives, New Labour, LibDems) to keep the redistribution from the lower classes going; it has worked very well because given how huge the gains have been in the favored areas most middle-class voters vote primarily on property rentierism.
In particular in the UK the governing thatcherite party has only ever lost elections when property prices fell (mid 1990s, late 2000s) or merely stalled (early 2020s).
It is the political power of booming property rents and prices that drives all the mechanisms used to keep them booming. Most people opposed to housing cost inflation focus on the mechanisms by which it is achieved and how to counter them, but what matters is the political will and the support of the middle-class voters, because given those new mechanisms can always be found.
The most important question for opponents of rentierism is how to persuade middle-class voters that higher wages, better pensions, less mean social insurance are better and in particular safer than massive property based redistribution from the lower classes.
«how to persuade middle-class voters that higher wages, better pensions, less mean social insurance are better and in particular safer than massive property based redistribution from the lower classes.»
DeleteThe basic problem of mass property rentierism is that in the long term it is unsustainable:
* If you read the "Telegraph" or the "Mail" it becomes clear that their model for economic prosperity is to be a BTL landlord with 3-4 properties and the ideal future for the UK is for everybody to be such a BTL landlord. The difficulty is that if everybody becomes a BTL landlord then there are not tenants, so in effect prosperity needs 3-4 tenants to pay for the 25-35% of landlord to have a good living standard.
* This holds true if one considers owner-occupiers as well as landlords. Indeed currently in the UK around 20-40% of families enjoy a large boost to their living standards thanks to property profits redistributed from the lower classes. Two lower class persons can hardly pay through rising rents and prices for the cruises, renovations, newer cars, retirement, travel adventures, etc... of one middle-class person.
* The problem is that history shows that rentierism is sustainable only if the rentiers are 1% of the population, perhaps at most 5-10%, certainly not 20-40%. This un-sustainability which first manifested in the mid-1990s and got fully exposed in the late 2000s GFC has been papered over by ballooning levels of private debt which has been bailed out with public debt (see the BoE booming balance sheet).
* The private and public debts are only sustainable as long as the balance of payments is supported by purchases of UK property deeds by foreign investors as that lowers interest rates. That is often "hot money" and if there is any period in which the doubling rate of southern property disappointing they will sell to avoid immobilizing their capital and that will collapse the whole UK economy and financial system.
https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/economy-speech-delivered-by-david-cameron
“It is hard to overstate the fundamental importance of low interest rates for an economy as indebted as ours… …and the unthinkable damage that a sharp rise in interest rates would do. When you’ve got a mountain of private sector debt, built up during the boom… …low interest rates mean indebted businesses and families don’t have to spend every spare pound just paying their interest bills. In this way, low interest rates mean more money to spare to invest for the future. A sharp rise in interest rates – as has happened in other countries which lost the world’s confidence – would put all this at risk… …with more businesses going bust and more families losing their homes.”
Note: the UK political and economic and financial systems have long been based on property speculation, and doubling-up has been at least since 2007 the largest source of "productivity" in the UK.
«what he can afford to take; but to what the farmer can afford to give." Ricardo formulated this as a general law, to wit that the rent of a piece of land will equal the additional monetary gain of its productive use relative to the production of a rent-free piece of land. [...] in terms of explaining what determines its price, is the rent of property, and specifically houses and flats. [...] Many people assume that the dynamic of this relationship works in the opposite direction: high house prices lead to high rents, and that rising house prices are simply the consequence of demand outstripping supply»
ReplyDeleteThat is indeed correct with an enormous qualification: demand outstripping supply in areas with plenty of jobs with good wages (or much less frequently with great amenities, which matter only to independently wealthy buyers or renters).
In effect as a rule property rent whether in buyer prices or tenancy costs are private taxes on wages, the higher the extraction on the wage the more an area has jobs and in particular jobs paying good wages. In England another factor is availability of "good schools". This called "von Thünen's law" (rent is inversely proportional to commuting costs, roughly):
https://www.thuenen.de/en/thuenen-institute/info-desk/johann-heinrich-von-thuenen
https://www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/casa/about/software/von-thunen-model
Therefore thatcherite governments have constantly sought to concentrate increases of jobs with good wages in areas already endowed with them, in the UK typically London and the south-East, in order to generate ever rising prices and rents in those areas; Crossrail in Greater London is the most obvious recent example, and HS2 and the Oxford-Cambridge corridor are other examples.
Note: prices and rents in those areas must keep rising because if they merely went flat they would then soon collapse because no middle class voters wants to put 100% of their savings plus borrow 5-10 times their gross income to speculate on property that does not yield big gains, especially with 4-5% nominal interest rates being available, and they would sell such an unprofitable speculation.
«US liberals like Ezra Klein and Derek Thompson argue that "abundance" can be achieved by simply rolling back regulations and striking out building codes»
ReplyDelete"Abundance" is indeed little more than reaganism misrepresented as a "progressive" policy and it used to be called “Laissez faire, laissez enricher” in the 19th century more recently it was described well by Peter Mandelson as a core "centrist" programme in 2002:
https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2002/jun/10/labour.uk
“in the urgent need to remove rigidities and incorporate flexibility in capital, product and labour markets, we are all Thatcherites now”
It is indeed also a programme against labor unionism:
https://inthesetimes.com/article/labor-unions-abundance-klein-thompson-cato
“Others, though, insist that unions stand in the way of achieving abundance, and view Klein and Thompson’s agnosticism towards labor as either misguided or a fig leaf to make their book palatable to elected Democrats. To these abundists, downright hostility toward organized labor is often a necessary precondition for abundance.
This anti-union hostility was clear at WelcomeFest [...] the self-proclaimed largest gathering of centrist Democrats. There, prominent writer Josh Barro declared that “when I look at policies in New York that stand in the way of Abundance, very often if you look under the hood, you eventually find a labor union at the end that’s the driver.”
«"Abundance" is indeed little more than reaganism misrepresented as a "progressive" policy»
DeleteFor a genuinely progressive notion of "abundance":
https://www.masongaffney.org/essays/Georges_Economics_of_Abundance.pdf
"George’s Economics of Abundance"
«the reluctance of volume builders to over-supply the market and so depress prices»
ReplyDeleteBut theoretically they could more than make up in higher volume with what they would lose in price... But they do not need to because the incentives do not require that:
* Most big builders are just fronts for big land owning corporations and trusts.
* Big landowning corporations can pay large bonuses and dividends not just on realizing gains via land sales, but also on *book* gains without land sales. Book profits are "profits".
* They just need to sell enough land every year to generate the cash flow to pay out the dividends and bonuses "covered" by those book profits, and keep accumulating unrealized gains on the unsold land as they expect their "sponsored" politicians to keep pumping up prices and rents. Middle class owner occupiers do something very similar by remortgaging (HELOCs) which is a big deal.
https://www.opendemocracy.net/ourkingdom/oliver-huitson/thatcher-black-gold-or-red-bricks
“Under Thatcher, this exploded to over £250bn across her premiership – a staggering 104% of GDP growth. [...] But Blair did his homework and let loose – as did Thatcher – a wave of cheap credit, financial deregulation, house price inflation and an equity withdrawal-led consumption boom. Withdrawals under Blair’s leadership totalled around £365bn, that’s a full 103% of GDP growth over the same period”
«When we talk of "the housing market" (singular) we are dealing in a fantasy. In reality, there are hundreds, if not thousands, of geographically limited housing markets, which estate and letting agents understand only too well. Goods (i.e. houses and flats) cannot be moved from one market to another, so prices must always reflect local circumstances. We also cannot easily choose to buy from alternative suppliers in cheaper markets. If I work in London but can't afford the rent, there's no point renting a flat in Sunderland.»
ReplyDeleteAnd this is point of von Thünen's law: proximity to sources of income, for most people jobs, makes prices and rents of property a private tax on those sources of income, to the point that that incomes net of housing costs tend to be similar across a country. Then what really matters is the distribution of jobs.
There is also the issue that the housing market is very illiquid as only a small fraction of houses are on the market (usually not quite 1%) so an increase in demand because of an increase in availability of jobs drawing in new buyers and tenants usually leads to sharp increases in prices and rents. The same happens for locations with amenities, and here is a beautiful example:
ttps://www.businessinsider.com/affordable-housing-crisis-us-west-coast-cause-explained-2023-9$
“Tucked in the far southwest corner of Colorado is the historic city of Durango. Built in the 19th century at a railroad junction, it's nestled in a bend of the Animas River as it flows through the magnificent San Juan Mountains. Stunning scenery and copious amenities helped attract 460 new residents to the town of 19,000 during the pandemic. That may not sound like a lot, but it was enough to juice median home prices by 50% in just three years, with them soaring from $500,000 in 2019 to over $750,000 by 2022.”
The same happened (but the attraction being jobs) a little more slowly but on a much bigger scale scale to London and the south-East thanks to decisive political action.
I never believed about "leveling up" if the "kicked behind" areas of the north etc. were to become rich in jobs then a lot of people would move out of the south-east and London to benefit from the availability of those jobs in areas with lower housing costs, and property prices in London and the south-east would collapse. Since 90% of bank lending in the UK goes to property speculation and obviously a large majority of that is for the south-east and London even a small fall in prices there would bankrupt several times over most UK banks (as happened in 2008-2010) and the political class would never tolerate that.
The other factor is that MPs, party officials, intellectuals, trade union officials, government officials, journalists, ... are almost all property owners (often with many properties owned between them and their close kin), and "turkeys do not vote for Christmas".
«But an even more prevalent omission in the popular macroeconomic discourse, which was once central to economics in the days of Adam Smith and David Ricardo, is the role of rent.»
ReplyDeleteThe neoclassical marginalist Economists like Marshall and Walras and other did talk of land of economic rent, it was expunged from Economics by J. B. Clark (using truly ridiculous shysterism) for political purposes as well argued by M. Gaffney:
https://www.masongaffney.org/publications/K2008_Keeping_Land_in_Capital_Theory.pdf
"Keeping Land in Capital Theory: Ricardo, Faustmann, Wicksell, and George"
https://www.masongaffney.org/publications/K1Neo-classical_Stratagem.CV.pdf
"Neo-classical Economics as a Stratagem Against Henry George," in Fred Harrison, "The Corruption of Economics."
https://www.masongaffney.org/publications/K9-StabileHGInfluenceonJBClarkMGComments.CV.pdf
"Stabile on George and Clark"
«That rents have grown over this period is not because people have felt that housing was a better choice for their discretionary expenditure, despite the relentless media propaganda, but because landlords have, in Smith's words, constantly recalibrated what the tenant can afford to give.»
ReplyDeleteI will insist on this because it misses the point: that “constantly recalibrated what the tenant can afford to give” could not have happened without the right conditions, and has happened only because there is a huge (20-40%) block of property rentiers which determines political priorities, and most MPs, party officials, journalists, government officials, local councilors, lawyers, managers, trade union officials, pensioners, academics, doctors, are member of that block of property rentiers.
Again what matters is to persuade at least a large fraction of that rentier block that higher wages, decent pensions, good social insurance, are better long-term for them than relying on property-based redistribution from the lower classes. Talking with them many say something like "Apres moi le deluge" as they could hardly care less about the long-term as they are already old.
For the others I guess that will only happen after an argentinian or soviet style collapse much worse than the 2008-2010 period, after barefoot scamps start begging in the streets of Sevenoaks and Guildford, or when grannies from Amersham or St. Albans end up selling their last clothes and pans on the pavements to get some money to eat.
https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:Rostov-on-don-russia-1992.jpg