Popular Tropes

And now for something completely different ...

Friday, 13 March 2020

We Are All Critics Now

We have become used to the idea that budgets should be viewed through the lenses of market confidence and personal impact - what it means for the FTSE-100 or a couple in a civil partnership with a dog and a Range Rover. As a result, we now struggle to analyse the politics of the Chancellor's announcement in anything other than the most superificial terms: that the left has somehow won the argument on investment or that the Tories have parked their tanks on Labour's lawn. This obviously highlights the extent to which class has been marginalised in mainstream discourse since the 1980s, but it also points to the way that budgets, as set-pieces of political theatre, have become dramatic "works" whose critique is dominated by the fisking of the IFS (Paul Johnson now has the equivalent clout of Frank Rich, the 1980s New York Times critic dubbed the "Butcher of Broadway") and the hunt for plagiarism (the "already announced" numbers that pad out the new). A consequence of this is the expectation of novelty and surprise, which obscures the extent to which budgets, as progress reports of a ship of state that has very limited manoeuvrability, reflect continuity. This is most obvious in the claim that this week's budget marks the long-heralded "end to austerity".

If you were serious about making the case, you would start by defining austerity. Living within our means hardly qualifies, given the continuing if shrinking deficit since 2010 and the steady rise in the national debt over most of the last decade, while the idea that we were doing more with less is flatly contradicted by persistently poor productivity. The belief that austerity is merely a ruse to shrink the state is also not borne out by the data. Though the public sector share of GDP has declined since the artificial highs of 2009-10, the current figure of just under 40% merely takes us back to the levels seen in the 2005-08 period. Though the cuts to public services have been severe, this has been offset by increasing demographic demand and poor GDP growth. Even the claim that austerity is more of a moral stance is belied by the triviality of its cultural impact, from Keep Calm and Carry On to the vogue for home-baking. What did change over the last ten years was a steady shift in public resources away from the poorest and most vulnerable. We were not all in it together. In the final analysis, austerity has simply been an active policy of inequality and there is little evidence that the government intends to bring that to an end.

Aside from the targeted funds for the NHS and the police, and the now traditional protection of old-age pensions, the punishment of public services continues. Despite election campaign promises there is no "solution" to the growing care crisis and I wouldn't hold my breath for anything radical turning up in the autumn. In reality, much of the extra funding for the government's nebulous "levelling up" will find its way into council care services, though this will undoubtedly be insufficient to both patch the holes and meet growing demand. Sending Treasury officials to a business park off the M1 or M6 doesn't distract from the lack of any substantive move towards greater fiscal devolution or the continuing squeeze on local authority budgets. Much of the promised infrastructure investment follows the usual pattern of preferential help for motorists and rail commuters. There is to be no large-scale investment in housing - i.e. social infrastructure - and the environmental measures are nowhere near sufficient to address climate change.


The investment in R&D is positive, but this has not really been an area that the UK has been lacking in. The perennial problem has been translating research into viable businesses and jobs, which is ultimately about the willingness of private sector investors to prefer domestic over foreign opportunities. The scaling back of Entrepreneurs' Relief is an admission that subsidising "value-creators" hasn't worked to boost British industry, but has rather served to further advance rentier interests. The failure to scrap it altogether indicates a continued desire to indulge an already advantaged class fraction that is a major contributor to the low productivity that bedevils the economy. Like the Catapult innovation centres, which sought to bridge the "valley of death" between primary research and commercialisation, the thinking behind this relief was that the state's role is to cultivate a climate of exploitation and hope the market takes the hint, rather than to seek to direct capital. As such, there has been no Damascene conversion to the merits of the postwar national economy. There will be no National Enterprise Board, let alone a Department of Economic Affairs.

The Covid-19 measures are focused not so much on stabilising the wider economy or supporting precarious workers as protecting small businesses through the suspension of business rates and the subsidising of sick pay (if the expectation is that most people will be infected then a blanket award of cash - i.e. helicopter money - would arguably be a sensible strategy, solving the gig worker problem at a stroke, but this would simply offend too many conservative sensibilities). One consequence of this SME indulgence will be the continued depression of productivity, essentially because more underperforming firms are being offered an end-of-life extension. Along with the likelihood that high street lenders, encouraged by the Bank of England, will show forbearance on loans, this means that the zombie army will march on. One potential consequence of this temporary relief is that reversing it later will become politically unappealing, just as unfreezing the annual increase in fuel duty has, so either business rate relief may become semi-permanent or pressure will increase for a downward revaluation, or at least reform of the current transitional rules.

The response to the pandemic is driven not merely by scientific advice but by assumptions about public health and governance. The suggestion that the science is being influenced by behavioural psychology more than epidemiology points to the voguish influence of the marketised approach to social control, in which the self-interest of utility maximisation is held to be the most powerful force that operates on society, but underlying this is an older policy tradition of "let nature take its course" that reflects a de haut en bas pessimism about both the morality and effectiveness of state intervention. This has echoes of the response by the British government to the Irish famine of the mid-nineteenth century, which was equally informed by the enlightened view of scientific experts influenced by contemporary political economy. Where once the population could be dismissed as "feckless", now we are told that the interventions being adopted by other countries would be counter-productive because of our susceptibility to "fatigue", a politer way of saying the same thing.


Martin Kettle was typical of the centrist response to the budget in evoking the halcyon years of Butskellism. The "postwar consensus" is an historical given among press commentators, but it has long been contested by actual historians. The Tories certainly accommodated themselves to the welfare state after 1945, but they voted against the NHS and consistently sought to support private healthcare thereafter, which established a consistent pattern: resist the extension of public welfare, concede it under electoral duress, and then work to preserve a private sphere that could form the foundation of an eventual reversal. For example, they supported comprehensivisation after Butler's tripartite education model was shown to be inadequate to the needs of a modern society, but they insisted on maintaining the privileges of public schools. Today, they hold the latter up as exemplars for privatised academies. Likewise, their attitude towards organised labour and their willingness to make concessions in the face of its demands was always grudging and reluctant, even before Ted Heath tried to take the miners on.

Kettle revealingly interprets the budget as not only a break with the post-1979 past but as a repudiation of the Conservative party's critics: "It is now lazier than ever to dismiss the Tories as mere neoliberals, compulsive austerians or even as the same old, same old". Given that the budget does not diverge from neoliberal orthodoxy (those infrastructure funds will predominantly go to private contractors), maintains austerity for most of the public realm, and is wholly consistent with traditional Tory practice, this is a heroic determination to refuse to see what is at the end of your nose. The Guardian editorial - We are all Keynesians now (a phrase misattributed to Richard Nixon in 1971) - was more sceptical, correctly noting that this budget was not about to empower workers or advance redistribution, but it revealed its impeccable Oxbridge breeding by wheeling out the old essay trope about the Tories' ruthless pragmatism: "Conservatives, however, are prepared to give up their principles for power. It is what makes the party such a formidable political force."

All administrations trim and compromise, but the suggestion that the Tories are particularly prone to this is a myth based on assumptions about their innate skill and temperament as "the natural party of government", not to mention starry-eyed biographies of Peel, Disraeli and Churchill. The history of the Conservative party over the twentieth century is one of a reluctance to give up old principles, from empire and public schools to the under-taxation of property, combined with an irreconcilable dissatisfaction with the postwar dispensation. This was obvious both in their attitude to Europe, where a deliberate self-delusion about free trade and a refusal to acknowledge the logic of integration led inexorably to Brexit, and in their ambivalence over Keynesian demand management and the narrowing of inequality, which eventually led to the embrace of Thatcherite neoliberalism. Commentators who claim that the Tories have wisely adjusted to changed realities are invariably liberals projecting what they consider to be the wisdom of centrist governance, hence their tendency to wheel out the quote usually misattributed to Keynes: "When the facts change, I change my mind". The truth is that Rishi Sunak's first budget is business as usual, and that would be even more obvious were it not for Covid-19.

8 comments:

  1. Herbie Kills Children13 March 2020 at 19:18

    The austerity we have seen is a war on the poorest and most vulnerable. That hasn't changed one jot as far as I can see.

    Real austerity is something different, maybe the consequences of the coronavirus will show us what actual austerity looks like!

    ReplyDelete
  2. «you would start by defining austerity.»

    Historically "austerity" means a fiscal *and* credit squeeze on *everbybody*, and in particular the most affluent, to reduce the foreign deficit (sometimes indirectly via a reduction of the state deficit).

    «the idea that we were doing more with less is flatly contradicted by persistently poor productivity.»

    Productivity, as in physical outputs per physical inputs, may well have increased, what has not increased is income per worker hour, quite a different measure.

    Anyhow poor income growth per worker hour is a government policy: since 1980 the rate of GDP-per-person growth has halved compared to the previous decades, to ensure that "inflationary" wage growth is low.

    «What did change over the last ten years was a steady shift in public resources away from the poorest and most vulnerable.»

    Note just public resources: private too. The redistribution from workers to rentiers from housing cost inflation has been much bigger than any cut in public services. What is immiserating most working families is not the cut in welfare, but the increasing burden of spending on housing.

    «austerity has simply been an active policy of inequality»

    My usual description is that there has been no "austerity" impacting all, but a large redistribution from squeezed workers to affluent rentiers.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. there has been no "austerity" impacting all, but a large redistribution from squeezed workers to affluent rentiers.

      The point I make in many comments and here is that for 40 years the incomes and wealth of a large minority of english voters have been booming, with rapid increases in living standards. Many "leftists" instead talk as if "the economy" has been shrinking for everybody. Those who vote for thatcherism largely do so because they are satisfied with the "booming" economy ("their" economy has indeed been booming) thanks to those they worship as economic geniuses, Thatcher, Blair, Osborne.

      Delete
  3. «the lack of any substantive move towards greater fiscal devolution or the continuing squeeze on local authority budgets.»

    But this statement is ridiculous: the “continuing squeeze on local authority budgets” is indeed “fiscal devolution”, as it is the result of the explicit goal of the Conservatives to cut the Revenue Support Grant that helps equalize spending per head between poor and rich areas, which is funded by national taxes. That is their explicit goal of the Conservatives is to achieve complete fiscal devolution.

    Also one of the signal policies of the Conservatives has been to enably by law fiscal devolution: local councils are free to increase local taxes as much as they want *as long as the increase is confirmed in a local referendum*.

    Of course local councils have almost never tried to do that as the local electorate will vote against any local tax increase: in poor areas because they cannot afford to pay more, and in rich areas because they don't need to.

    The long term goal is to segregate poor people in poor areas and rich people in rich areas, by using property rents and prices as the filter, by creating one-"rate" housing estates, and then to switch most taxation and spending from the national to the local level, to prevent most redistribution.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. I'm talking about fiscal devolution in the sense of local authorities' discretion over expenditure, rather than their revenue-raising powers (which, as you note, are dubious because of the constraints). This discretion has been whittled down by the increasingly prescriptive attitude of central government. Councils thus face a double-whammy of squeezed budgets and less room for manoeuvre.

      Delete
    2. local authorities' discretion over expenditure [...] has been whittled down by the increasingly prescriptive attitude of central government

      But then please give New Labour and the Conservatives credit for cunning: the central government prescriptions are both *lower bounds* and pretty minimal, to protect the New Labour and Conservative central governments from accusations that they allow local councils to be mean; local councils as far as I know are entirely free to provide better services than the central government minimal prescriptions allow, if they can raise the revenue, for example by winning a referendum on local tax increases.

      The constraint that matters is therefore on the revenue side, not the lower bounds to certain categories of service provision, which are in effect unfunded mandates in many areas.

      Delete
    3. Herbie Kills Children17 March 2020 at 20:34

      Interestingly councils have been attempting to undermine their statutory responsibilities. For example they have a statutory responsibility to keep the highways safe but have spent the last 20 years trying to redefine what that means.

      Another example is home to school transport, a piffling expenditure but nevertheless they have attempted to abrogate their responsibilities by redefining who is eligible.

      They have also cut back on meals on wheels. there are numerous examples.

      The thing is these measures were the result of Gershon review rather than the 2008 crisis.

      Councils have been actively seeking to make services worse while bulking up their marketing departments to inform everyone of good news stories while conveniently ignoring all the cuts they were making. Concultation was another big fraud they came up with, pretend to engage with the public but do whatever it is they had already decided.

      Now they use the climate crisis to justify massive tax hikes, god only knows what they will have in store for us when they invoke the coronavirus!

      The point is that Blairism firmly turned councils from local provision (which they were admittedly inadequate at) to being private in all but name. The Tories will finish the job off.

      Delete
  4. The history of the Conservative party over the twentieth century is one of a reluctance to give up old principles, from empire and public schools to the under-taxation of property, combined with an irreconcilable dissatisfaction with the postwar dispensation.

    This is just appearances, the Conservatives are indeed really tactically adaptable, just like the Republicans in the USA, they don't have a fixed ideology. Because their role is to protect the interests of a minority of incumbents, by assembling coalitions that support that; and which incumbents are dominant in the party changes with time, and which coalitions turn a minority of incumbents into a governing majority also changes with time too. Here is Grover Norquist explaining it pithily and with some obvious omission for the current USA conservative coalition:

    «But on the vote-moving primary issue, everybody's got their foot in the center and they're not in conflict on anything. The guy who wants to spend all day counting his money, the guy who wants to spend all day fondling his weaponry, and the guy who wants to go to church all day may look at each other and say, "That's pretty weird, that's not what I would do with my spare time, but that does not threaten my ability to go to church, have my guns, have my money, have my properties, run by my business, home-school my kids.»

    The omission here is that the "guy who wants to spend all day counting his money" is actually the dominant partner driving legislation, the other two components are only there to turn the monority into a majority.

    Sunak's first budget is business as usual

    That's not a suprrise, because while the Conservatives are indeed very opportunistic as to the coalitions they assemble, they are very consistent and long term planners about their core role, protecting the interests of the dominant incumbents. So for example they have adopted decades ago a strategy of "boiling the frog", pushing the interests of incumbents only a little bit forward every year, as over the years this builds up in a huge shift, as M Thatcher wrote to Hayek in 1982:

    «I was aware of the remarkable success of the Chilean economy in reducing the share of Government expenditure substantially over the decade of the 70s. The progression from Allende's Socialism to the free enterprise capitalist economy of the 1980s is a striking example of economic reform from which we can learn many lessons. [...] Our reform must be in line with our traditions and our Constitution. At times the process may seem painfully slow. But I am certain we shall achieve our reforms in our own way and in our own time.»

    The current shape of the UK economy is not too far from the goal of a Pinochet-style economy.

    ReplyDelete